Real estate has been a great investment for so long that people think it always will be. This is a mistake. I don’t think it will.
Powerful forces have been raising housing prices for decades. But they are now petering out, even reversing. As time passes, housing prices might shrink.
To understand this, we need a very simple rule: the law of supply and demand.
This article refers mainly to developed economies.
Have Housing Prices Always Gone Up?
No.
But you wouldn’t know that, because all your life, housing prices have grown:
Our living memory of housing prices only goes back to the 1950s.1 In that time, real housing prices2 have quadrupled.
But what happens if we look a bit farther back in time?
Prices only started growing after 1950!
Data from even farther back gets a bit spottier because few countries have good records, but the finding generally stands. This is Amsterdam:
This is for Belgian cities:
Housing prices used to be very stable. So why did they grow so dramatically in recent times?
Simply because demand has outstripped supply.
A. Demand
What drives the demand for housing?
More people
Who want to live in the same place: cities
Who generally want bigger houses
And who also might want fewer people living in the same household
Each one of these four trends has been growing incredibly in the past few decades, but is unlikely to keep growing and may even reverse.
1. Population Growth
The more people there are, the more housing we need to shelter them.
It’s true that population has grown since we were hunter-gatherers, but it has exploded in recent times in ways we have a hard time fathoming:
More people meant more demand for housing. But will this trend continue? As you can probably surmise, it won’t.
The populations of Japan, China, and Europe are already shrinking.
The US is mainly growing because of immigration (which we’ll discuss later), but even there, the growth rate is going to be lower in the future than in the past. That is true for the entire world.
Of course, all of this is driven by the fertility rate, which is shrinking all over the world, is already below replacement rate in most countries, and will likely become the case in all of them.
To be explicit: More people means higher housing prices.
OK so one of the biggest drivers of real estate price increases was simply more people. But it’s not just that. They also all wanted to live in the same places!
2. Urbanization
More and more people want to live in cities, but that’s quite a recent phenomenon! In nearly all countries, by the middle of the 1800s, less than 20% of the population was urban!
When everyone began moving to cities, demand on urban housing increased, and prices with them: the denser the area, the higher the prices.
The urbanization rate can’t keep increasing forever. When it went from ~10% in 1800 to ~90% in 2020, that was a 9x increase. From there, at most it can reach 100%, which is only a 10% increase. Therefore, this huge driver of demand for urban land that has existed for 200 years is now dead in developed countries, and might even revert given remote work.
OK, so we used to have more people who wanted to live in the same place in the last 200 years, and especially in the last 75.
But they also wanted to be less crowded!
3. Household Size
The number of people per household has shrunk dramatically over the last couple of centuries:
If you zoom in on the most recent years, you’ll see that this trend has stopped too, or even reverted. The drive to live in homes with fewer family members grew housing demand until the 1990s, but has barely contributed since.
The same is true in Europe, where household size (as in people per household) is even lower:
Will we get to a world with one person per household? 0.5, if each person owns more than one home? Maybe. But based on the trend of the last few decades, it looks like this trend is now dead. Why? Because its main driver is family size:
And families can’t get much smaller than a couple and half a child.3
They do want bigger houses though.
4. Bigger houses
As family sizes shrunk, house size grew.
This is how we arrived at houses with one room per child, coming from a world where we packed many people in one room.
This trend seems to be true in other rich countries.
But the more they grow, the less valuable each new square foot is. Yes, each person can have a room and an office, but at some point they have enough empty rooms and don’t want more. This trend will stop. And until then, it will decelerate.
In other words: Over the last few decades, there have been:
More people
Moving to cities
Who increasingly want to live alone
In bigger houses
These trends meant there has been a huge increase in demand for housing land since 1950. But now all these trends are stopping or reversing.4
While demand grew, supply didn’t keep up.
B. Supply
One inconvenient thing about houses is that they occupy volume. As a result, you can only grow your supply of housing by growing horizontally or vertically.
1. Horizontal Supply and the Marchetti Constant
In How Transportation Technologies Shape Cities, I explained how the main driver of city size is transportation technologies. It’s easy to understand why: People don’t like commuting more than 30 minutes—the Marchetti Constant. When new transportation technologies speed up the commute, city footprints can increase.
As such, city size was limited for thousands of years. Until the train arrived, and then streetcars, bikes, and eventually cars.
When your average commute speed goes from 5 km/h walking to 50 km/h by car, you can travel 10x farther in 30 minutes, and the edge of a city is pushed 10x farther.
But the land available increases by the square of that, making the city 100x bigger!
The result is that the car increased the supply of land for housing by 10-100x compared to walking!
But that is only useful if you own a car. Car ownership has increased dramatically in the last 70 years:
In the US, we’ve reached saturation: There are about two cars per household, and that number hasn’t grown since the late 1980s.
This means nearly every household can have a car, nearly everybody can drive to work, and car ownership doesn’t limit city size.
Consequently, over the last few decades, cities stopped growing horizontally: They had grown dramatically in the 1950s-2000s along with car ownership, until it wasn’t a limiting factor anymore. The edges of cities was the limiting factor.
You can probably get a sense of that in your daily life. When did your city suburbs grow the most? Probably in the 1950s-2000s. After that, new suburbs were ever farther from the city center, less compelling. This limited housing supply, which drove prices up.
But this trend is now ending, because remote work has reduced commute time to zero, so cities’ potential size is infinite.
Remote Work
If the car can allow people to live dozens of kilometers away from downtown because they can travel at 30-50 km per hour, what happens when they can travel at 300,000 km per second? That’s the speed of light, which is basically the speed of your video call. When you work remotely, you are no longer limited by the Marchetti constant. At most, you’re limited by the timezone.
People couldn’t work remotely until very recently. Now, they can get electricity and Internet from virtually anywhere:
Many people will go to live in rural and semi-urban areas, where prices are lower, and safety and quality of life are higher. The entire world is now potential housing supply. What do you think that will do to housing prices in the long run?
2. Vertical Supply and Sky Highways
At the very same time that transportation technology was increasing supply horizontally, another type of technology was increasing the supply vertically: construction and elevators.
Until the 1800s, buildings were at most six floors tall because taller ones would crumble under their own weight. But steel framing and reinforced concrete changed that, technically allowing buildings to grow taller.
It’s one thing to make them possible, another thing to make them enjoyable. In the past, higher floors were for poor people because nobody wanted to climb six flights of stairs.
The elevator, invented at the end of the 1900s, changed that. It allowed people to reach any floor easily. Coupled with the advent of electricity and things like water pumps for water access in high floors, elevators didn’t just make higher floors possible; they made them better. Now you’d rather have the penthouse than the ground floor. This is only 100 years old.
As skyscrapers filled the skyline, people’s dwellings ascended into the heights, and this new supply kept prices controlled in the first half of the 20th century.
Then, we stopped building up.
NIMBYism
Paris built the Tour Eiffel. Then every Parisian thought it was ugly, and they decided to stop building tall buildings. Later, in the skyscrapers craze, they decided to build the Tour Montparnasse. They then thought it was ugly, and banned all new skyscrapers—they pushed them outside of the city, to La Défense. A few decades later, construction started again, and stopped again. If you live in a Western country, this might sound familiar to you.
There are height restriction laws for buildings in most cities in Europe and North America. These have prevented buildings from growing up, limiting the supply of housing, and driving prices up.5
This trend might not change, in which case supply will remain restricted. But if it changes, will it be for more restriction, or more freedom?
It’s hard to be more restrictive than today, where many cities can’t build anything, especially upwards. What is more likely is that building restrictions will be reduced, pushed by the YIMBY movement (Yes In My BackYard). Tired of NIMBY, they started fighting back. Across the US, building restrictions have been falling.
Building restrictions are also likely to be relaxed for another reason: As demand shrinks, prices will drop, cities will compete to attract more people, and building restrictions are likely going to be relaxed.
If you have to bet whether restrictions are going to tighten or release, I’d say it’s more likely they’ll either stay the same or release, which means more supply for housing, and lower prices.
Bringing It Home
Until the Industrial Revolution, the population of most Western countries grew very slowly.
Cities were small, most people lived in rural areas, and there was no such thing as “housing prices” that really mattered.
Starting in the 1800s, all these trends blew up. Populations exploded, urbanization exploded, people started getting crammed in urban homes…
In some places, prices exploded. But in many others, they didn’t because as demand went up, people simply settled around the tiny centers of existing cities. Soon, these cities could be built up and out thanks to technologies like elevators, reinforced concrete, trains, and cars, adding floods of supply to the incessant demand for more housing.
Over the last 75 years, demand for urban housing was driven by:
Higher population growth
More urbanization
More homes per person
Bigger homes
But supply ground to a halt horizontally and vertically:
Cities grew as much as they could horizontally and the edge of our car suburbs hit the Marchetti constant.
NIMBYs restricted building up, limiting supply
Now, we’re entering a world where all these trends are slowing down or reversing:
In demand:
The population is shrinking or soon will
Urbanization has reached its limits
We have all the homes we need per person. That growth is stopping.6
Homes keep getting bigger, but that trend is slowing every year
In supply:
Remote work eliminates the need to live close to work, which means the entire world becomes potential housing land supply
Building restrictions can’t get any tighter, and will likely be relaxed
We’re moving from a world where people have only experienced growing housing prices, to one where they are likely to shrink.
Does that sound like a world where real estate will be as good an investment as it used to be?
Not to me. That’s why I don’t invest in real estate.
Of course, there are more factors that influence real estate: housing vs commercial, certain cities vs others, interest rates, beach properties, income, immigration, home ownership, the timing of all of this, and more. I will cover these in this week’s premium article. I will also cover examples that illustrate all these trends already happening. Subscribe to read it!
None of this is investment advice. Please don’t invest based on this type of article. You should consider this purely informational or entertainment. This is me sharing how I think about the problem, and nothing else. Please talk with expert investment advisors before making important investment decisions.
99% of you reading this are most likely 95 years old or younger. You probably didn’t track housing prices until you were in your 20s. That means virtually all of you have only tracked the prices of housing in the last 75 years, meaning 1950 and later.
That is, controlling for inflation.
Or divorced parents of a single child. If they did, they would increase the number of houses per person, but the population would collapse faster, and housing prices would plummet anyway.
Except for house size: It’s not completely stopping or reversing, but it is decelerating. So it still counts as a contribution in reducing the growth in demand.
This is an interesting debate, because of course denser cities are more expensive, which means that building more increases prices, rather than decreasing them. But this is true in each individual city studied independently: If one grows vertically and not another, it will have higher density, which will bring more wealth, so it will attract people from another city that isn’t growing as much. It’s “stealing wealth” from the flatter city into the taller city. But if instead of looking at cities individually, you look at them as a whole—say, an entire country—then increasing height everywhere would release supply constraints and would reduce average housing prices. I will discuss this more in the premium article.
Although this is potentially not true in the future. We’ll talk about it in the premium article.
Good article for a generic warning but there is a lot missing in your analysis.
First, real estate is really local. Since buildings cannot be moved (generally), they cannot be considered as a commodities. Living in Manhattan is not like living in new Jersey for a multiple reasons although the two locations are only few miles away. Making general statements on the entire world cannot be precise.
Second, real estate is not just residential. Hospitality and logistics are booming, office market is shrinking and retail is softly recovering after 5 years of collapsing. Any sector have different cycles which follows different pace and direction.
Third, you ignored innovation, renovation and conversions. Old buildings cannot be converted often into modern space so they will lose their values unless in extraordinary locations while more modern products will preserve their intrinsec value. On the other hand, in some specific locations old resi building can be demolished and converted in something else. So again, it depends on the (micro) location.
Fourth, the analysis pre WWII is difficult to compare to our next future. Before the 1940 in most of the world there was no need for a permit to build a house. You could be bulding everywhere, you did not need any connections with sewer, eletricity network, etc. Developing today is getting harder for several reasons amongst which environmental impact valuations, longer planning procedures, political willingness, physical constraints, etc especially in the most demanded (again) locations.
As someone said in the past, do not forget the 3 most important elements in real estate: location, location and location.
Recently was pointed to another great post about this. Works in progress, "the housing theory of everything". Expensive housing has some really bad, often unexpected, downstream effects on the economy. This provides another huge incentive for governments to tackle the crisis.
Should be obvious that housing is a bubble, growth on the order of 100 of % are not an indicator of a sustainable model. In terms of rent, people are already paying like 40-50% of their net income for rent, can't go much higher than that without inciting a revolution...